Saturday, August 13, 2022

TUTORIAL: [M21422 Economic History of Early India] Write a review of R. S. Sharma's Early Medieval Indian Society: A Study in Feudalization

COURSE NAME: M21422 Economic History of Early India 

M. A. SEMESTER 1

TUTORIAL 2                         

TUTORIAL TOPIC: Write a review of R. S. Sharma's Early Medieval Indian Society: A Study in Feudalization. 

SUBMITTED BY: Pranav Kushwaha

[DISCLAIMER: The following tutorial is being shared so students of CHS, JNU can get some idea regarding how a tutorial is to be written. This tutorial is by no means of high quality, and you might find some factual, spelling, and grammatical errors.

In the original file that I submitted, (i) the numbers in the square brackets were used to denote footnotes and were written in superscripts, and (ii) there was no dedicated section titled 'Endnotes', as each page contained footnotes. Endnotes are acceptable, but I'd advise you to use footnotes instead. Better yet, confirm from your professor what is required.]


                       

 

 

Book Review:

R. S. Sharma, Early Medieval Indian Society: A Study in Feudalisation, Kolkata: Orient Longman Limited, 2001.

 

R S Sharma’s Early Medieval Indian Society: A Study in Feudalisation presents to its readers a comprehensive account of the various social, political, economic, and religious aspects of the early medieval Indian society. The book also goes to great length to describe how these aspects both influenced and were influenced by the process of feudalization that took place during this period. The book makes use of a number of primary and secondary sources, as well as the experience and expertise that the author brings to the table. The book is divided into nine chapters, each dealing with a different issue to cover the whole discussion at hand.

 

 

The first chapter, “Transition from Ancient to Medieval”, begins with the question of how we should define historical periods. If one follows the European model, one is left with the following results: Hinduism is linked with the ancient period, the arrival of Islam marks the beginning of the medieval period, and the establishment of colonial rule and the coming of Christianity starts the so-called modern period. As the author shows, linking historical periods with religion is highly problematic; for example, countries that always maintained one state religion would perpetually be stuck in one time period. The author argues that it was land grants that “ultimately transformed ancient Indian society into medieval society[1]. He also states that the decline of trade with the western world by the sixth century and the Arab middlemen reaping most of the benefits of Indo-Southeast Asian and Indo-Chinese trade resulted in the decay of towns, especially in the post-Gupta period.[2] The proliferation of castes, development of local languages and scripts, the rise of tantrism, and the early concept of bhakti marked the transition from the ancient to the medieval.

 

 

The beginning of the second chapter, “The Kali Age: A Period of Social Crisis”, explains the Kali Age as a period of time when dharma has lost three of its four legs, a period when rituals are neglected and the duties associated with the Varṇa System are not performed by the people. After focusing on the descriptions of social disorder during the Kali Yuga – as predicted by texts such as the Harivaśa – the chapter then focuses on a historical understanding of the Kali Yuga. In this regard, it can be argued that the beginning of the Kali Age was marked by the desertion of settlements from the 3rd century CE, coinciding with the decline of the Kuśāṇa and the Sātvāhanas empires.[3] A lot of focus has been placed upon the rulers imposing unnecessary taxes and using forced labour to meet their luxurious demands. People resorted to migration as socio-economic conditions worsened, and this resulted in rural expansion. Moreover, land grants in tribal areas brought previously alienated people into the Varṇa System, making farmers out of the people belonging to the native tribes.[4] People with financial means also fought for superior social status in a bid to be recognised for their contributions towards the functioning of society. Lastly, the forced employment of the Śudras in agricultural fields also declined during the Gupta age. Therefore, the author concludes that the “Kali Crisis of the late third and fourth centuries” provided the necessary elements which would react and result in the feudalisation of Indian society.[5]

 

 

The third chapter, “The Nature of Indian Feudalism”, begins with the argument that although feudalism varies across socio-political and historical contexts, there exist some basic and universal fundamental aspects that cannot be ignored. One of these fundamental aspects is the relationship between the landlord and the peasant, and the exploitation of the latter by the former.[6] The texts written by Yājñavalkya, Bṛhaspati, and Vyāsa, as well as the Gupta inscriptions, talk about the hierarchy established within the environment of cultivable land.[7] Land grants ultimately established the “superior rights of the landlord at the cost of both the king and the peasantry[8] which allowed the grant beneficiary to exploit the peasants even more; these peasants were liable to be evicted at the whim of the landlord. On the other hand, the state was able to collect its taxes via these landowners, as a result of which the rulers were able to gain legitimacy and secure their right to rule. Irrigation infrastructure – like wells, embankments, ponds, etc. – was also established to support agriculture and laws were made to punish those who would damage these constructions. The Indian system of feudalism, the author argues, differed from the European model of feudalism where the feudal lords depended on serfs to cultivate their land. Here, the ruling class created an intermediary landed class – the latter collected taxes for the former while exploiting the peasants.

 

 

The fourth chapter, “Paucity of Metallic Coinage”, begins with the argument that the study of coins is valued far more for understanding political history, and that not enough importance is given to the study of coins for understanding economic history. The author argues that the introduction of coins transformed the economy from taxation mechanism to trade methods to establishing relationships between people at different levels of socio-political hierarchy. Punch-marked coins were the norm during the Mauryan period, and by the Gupta period, coins of gold, copper, and a number of other metals were in use. Although coins continued to be in use by local dynasties, the post Gupta period saw an overall scarcity in coinage.[9] This scarcity seems to have come to an end circa 1000 CE, when coins of gold and other metals were reissued by Indian dynasties and trade flourished yet again. In the subsequent centuries, agricultural expansion, technological breakthroughs, rise of new, powerful dynasties – such as the Coḷas, Cāḷukyas, Kalacuris, Candellas, Cāhmanas, Paramāras, etc. – contributed towards the development of trade and communication with the rest of the world.[10]

 

 

The fifth chapter, “Aspects of Royal Land Charter (Rājaśāsana) and Property Inheritance”, is divided into two parts. The first part, titled “Rājaśāsana and its Legal Aspects”, introduces to the reader the “four feet of a lawsuit” as given in Kauṭilya’s Arthśāstra. These are – in increasing order of importance such that each successive category supersedes the previous category – dharma (law), vyavhāra (transactions of property, wage, debts, etc.), carita, and rājaśāsana (royal orders).[11] The rājaśāsana was invoked in several situations, especially in the case of a land dispute (kṣetraja or kṣetrajavāda).[12] Due to its utmost importance, forging of rājaśāsanas also took place. To counter this, several rules were laid down which provided for the verification and interpretation of these rājaśāsanas. Since the interpretation was to be carried out in a sabhā that barred the entry of the śudras, they were unable to get justice in land dispute matters.[13]

The second part, titled “Property and Inheritance Laws: Social and Economic Implications”, explains that according to the Dharmasūtras, there existed different means of acquiring property for members of each Varṇa in the Varṇa system. Gupta law provided that mere possession (bhukti) of property did not prove ownership, and that proper documentation (āgama) was required as proof.[14] Vidyādhana – property acquired due to teaching or sacrificial fee – could not be shared.[15] Thus, we see that a number of provisions had been made for the protection as well as the inheritance of property, and the state played an important role in regulating both the practices.

 

 

In the sixth chapter, “Changes in Social Structure”, we see that the frequent land grants led to the creation of new socio-economic classes that did not exist in the Vara system. For example, we see the rise of the yastha community. Distributed into a number of sub-groups, the social class of writers eventually came to be recognized as one single group. The yasthas acted as scribes, maintaining records of land grants, which could then be used for settling any future land disputes. These yasthas were also known as karaṇa, lekhaka, adhikṛta, etc.[16] Similarly, different classes of people came into existence who would keep track of land grants and property divisions. The author argues that the medieval period also saw a rise in the status of the śudras and a decline in that of the vaiśyas, as the former were employed in agriculture while the decline of trade negatively affected the latter.[17] There also occurred a differentiation within the Śudra community, as they were divided into two categories: sat (pure) and asat (impure). Moreover, a number of mixed castes also came up during this period.[18] This proliferation of castes was not limited to the lower sections of the Vara system. For example, the author mentions that although many Rajputs had originated from the Kśatriya class, several tribes – like the Cāḷukyas, Candelas, and Pālas – were recognized as Kśatriyas by the brahmins after performing certain rituals. Several central Asian peoples were inducted into the Kśatriya warrior class as well.[19]

 

 

The seventh chapter, “Dimensions of Peasant Protest”, explains that peasant protests could take many forms. One of the easiest ways of doing that was to personally complain to the king during royal visits. Even brahmins would lead several protests, with their own agenda of outthrowing those brahmins who enjoyed a better economic position due to the land grants. Yet another method was to desert the village en masse, and although necessary, it must not have been easy. One of the harder and bloodier ways of protests has been observed in the case of 11-13th century Andhra and Karnataka, where peasants would have to resort to launching attacks against the landlords – when the landlord didn’t listen to the peasant complaints – and the landlords could then burn the standing crop to punish the peasants.[20] Measures were also taken to prevent the peasants from mobilising in the first place. Since they were part of the same community (defined by caste or kin), the landholders would often impose this sense of “belonging” to deter the peasant from causing any upheaval. Religion also played a part in keeping social uproar in check, as both landlords and peasants were required to give gifts to temples and participate in community feasts.[21] The author also describes several examples of revolts that took place during the early medieval period across India in great detail.

 

 

 

The eighth chapter, “Economic and Social Basis of Tantrism”, begins with a historical understanding and description of Tantrism. Since Tantrism did not discriminate between the people on the basis of their Vara or gender, women and men (especially those belonging to the śudra category) flocked to Tantrism in large numbers. Tāntrika functioned as astrologers and physicians and were thus an important part of the social order. Shrines of the mother goddess, who defines Tantrism, were first recognized by the Brahmanical order in the sixth century.[22] Tantrism spread to tribal societies and was even influenced by Buddhism and Jainism, and we even find Tantric texts with Shaivite and Vaishnavite influence.[23] The chapter goes into great detail in discussing the plethora of Tantric texts written throughout the medieval period, how land grants were made in the name of Tantrism, and how it influenced the larger Brahmanical order as well as specific sects like Shaivism and Vaishnavism. The chapter concludes with the fact that attempts at integrating aspects of Tantrism with Brahminism worked as many Brahmins took to Tantrism.

 

 

The ninth chapter, “The Feudal Mind”, argues that owing to the socio-economic basis of feudalism, there was little to no mobility possible in the feudal system. But this system of hierarchy – king at the top, followed by the land grant beneficiaries, and then the peasants – did not limit itself to agriculture or economy. Aspects of this hierarchy were also reflected in the construction of temples, the adoption of epithets by rulers, and medieval mythologies. The author argues that due to the propagation of the belief that destiny was everything, that even karma was pre-determined by destiny, peasants developed a sense of apathy and helplessness.[24] The language used in inscriptions and land charters establishes the subservient nature of grant receivers in relation to the grant donors. During this period, the concept of bhakti came to be associated with service and liberation. A bhakta would make offerings to God, and He would give the bhakta His blessings in the form of prasāda. These ideals of bhakti were followed by peasants as well. The author argues that due to the close relationships between the peasant and the overlord, between the various feudal lords, and between the feudal lords and the king, the bhakti cult gained a wide base of support.[25]

 

 

The given book traces the social, political, economic, and religious aspects of India across the early medieval period and aptly explains the relationship between these factors and the rise of feudalism that took place within the given period. The decline in agriculture and trade that marked the post-Gupta period came to an end by the tenth-eleventh century; new land was brought under cultivation due to which agricultural expansion took place and trade flourished. This was accompanied by the rise of new kingdoms and dynasties. The practice of land grants created several new socio-economic classes while several other classes saw their importance reduced. A peasant’s rights over the cultivated land were also negatively affected. As a result, several peasant uprisings also took place. In the religious sphere, Tantrism rose into existence, accepting people from all walks of life into its fold. Overall, the early medieval period was a period of major transformations, and the book perfectly captures this fact.

 

 

 

Pranav Kushwaha

Enrolment Number: 21/61/HH/063

Semester 1

M. A. Ancient History (ANCM), CHS, JNU



ENDNOTES

[1] p. 18.

[2] pp. 27-28.

[3] pp. 48-49.

[4] p. 75

[5] p. 76.

[6] p. 80.

[7] Ibid.

[8] p. 92.

[9] P. 126.

[10] pp. 151-153.

[11] p. 163.

[12] p. 174-175.

[13] pp. 175-177.

[14] p. 179.

[15] p. 184.

[16] p. 194-195.

[17] p. 197-198.

[18] p. 200-202.

[19] pp. 206-207.

[20] p. 216.

[21] p. 233.

[22] p. 247.

[23] p. 255.

[24] p. 277.

[25] p. 280.

No comments:

Post a Comment

Thank you for reading today's entry. Feel free to leave a comment. I'd love to read your feedback!